motivation

When thinking about rules in the context of health, the most common defaults are to the Food and Drug Administration (FDA) as the regulator of pharmaceuticals and medical devices, and to the Centers for Medicare & Medicaid Services (CMS) which provides healthcare insurance coverage to 100 million Americans. This makes sense as the rules of FDA and CMS combine to largely determine which healthcare products are marketable and how much they will be sold for.

The general idea of a “rule,” though, can be read to encompass a wide-range of things including statutes, regulations, common law, guidelines, contracts, norms, corporate policies, and unspoken practices. At the intersection of health and technology, each of these rule categories applies, and each has tangible effect on health outcomes.

Digitalis Research is particularly interested in how rules create the context for innovation, finance, and justice in health and technology. For example, basic science research has become the subject of an increasingly open confrontation between those that view scientific knowledge as a common good to be shared and those that see it as a commodity to be exploited for private economic gain.

Scientists traditionally strive to be the first person to make an important discovery and communicate this advance in knowledge to the broader community.  The customary rewards for being first to discover include high-profile publications, important prizes, and more and easier grant funding.   This framework for science is seen to drive the rapid and open communication and use of new knowledge.

Since the passage of the Bayh-Dole Act in 1980 (a rule in the form of a statute), scientists who arrive at new knowledge first have, in addition to the customary rewards, an additional perk—the opportunity for their universities to own patents on their discoveries.  The ownership of patents allows institutions (and individual scientists) to exploit their findings for their institutional (and personal) economic benefit.  This private benefit, though, slows the communication and may limit the use of that new knowledge.  This framework for science allows the privatization of knowledge for the economic benefit of the discoverer.

Should there be profit in knowledge and how should our rules guide the balance between motivating private investment and supporting the public good?

open
questions

1

How do humans discover new rules?

2

What determines when, where, and how known rules are implemented?

3

Why do successful rules fail to be copied and reused?

4

How should we regulate new knowledge?

5

How should we regulate the unknown?

6

Is there a category of “forbidden knowledge”? If so, how should we define it and regulate it? Does the free availability of information change our definition of “forbidden knowledge”?

7

Does/how does AI promise to transform citizen involvement in rule-making?

8

Can good rules spur innovation?

9

How should we use rules to protect privacy?

10

What is the role of speed in rule-making (both in terms of the speed of development of new technologies and the speed of rule-making itself)?

11

Do rules drive history?

12

Decades of focusing on basic research and the tangible outputs it generates (e.g., journal articles, patents, and licenses) hasn’t produced many new organizational structures that improve upon our ability to translate new knowledge into practical solutions.  Is this failure due to an over-emphasis on individual technologies rather focusing on a better set of rules to support innovation broadly?

13

The United States’ Genetic Information Non-Discrimination Act of 2008 provides special protections for genetic information -- is this the correct information set to be worried about?

curation

BOOKS

Code and Other Laws of Cyberspace

Lawrence Lessig / Basic Books / 1999

“In [cyberspace], code is the most significant form of law, and it is up to lawyers, policymakers, and especially citizens to decide what values that code embodies.”

Athena Unbound

Peter Baldwin / The MIT Press / 2023

“Why and how scholarly knowledge should be free for all.”

ARTICLES

Why the Future Doesn’t Need Us

Bill Joy / Wired / April 2000

“The 21st-century technologies—genetics, nanotechnology, and robotics (GNR)—are so powerful that they can spawn whole new classes of accidents and abuses.”

Forbidden Knowledge

Joanna Kempner et al / Science / 2005

“Forbidden knowledge embodies the idea that there are things that we should not know.”

The First Patented G.M.O.

Rhea Purohit / Asimov Press / 2024

“The Supreme Court case that built the biotechnology industry.”

Open Biotechnology: 

Licenses Needed

Yann Joly / Nature Biotech / 2010

“Open biotechnology may be the ideal solution to ensure scientific progress and the realization of the common good, but it has yet to deliver on its promises.”

Closing the Access Gap for Health Innovations:

An Open Licensing Proposal for Universities

Samantha Chaifetz et al / Globalization and Health / 2007

“Forbidden knowledge embodies the idea that there are things that we should not know.”

PAPERS

How the FDA Impedes Innovation:

A Case Study in Overregulation

Michael Mandel / Progressive Policy Institute / 2011

“Is the FDA unintentionally choking off cost-saving medical innovation?”

Assessing the FDA via the Anomaly of Off-Label Drug Prescribing

Alexander T. Tabarrok / The Independent Review / 2000

“The implications of off-label uses of pharmaceuticals for the FDA’s regulatory power over new drugs.”

Contracts as Technology

Kevin E. Davis / NYU Law Review / 2013

“This Article analyzes innovations in contractual documents using the same kind of framework that is used to analyze other kinds of technological innovation.”

The Effects of Business Practices, Licensing, and Intellectual Property On Development and Dissemination of the Polymerase Chain Reaction: Case Study

Joe Fore Jr. et al. / Journal of Biomedical Discovery and Collaboration / 2006

“Given its essential role in the world of molecular biology and its commercial success, [PCR] technology can serve as a case study for evaluating the effects of patenting biological research tools on biomedical research.”

Contract Theory and the Limits of Contract Law

Alan Schwartz & Robert E. Scott / Yale Law Journal / 2003

An Introduction to the Law & Economics of Information

Tim Wu / Columbia Law and Economics Working Paper No. 482. /  2016

“[This] review questions if the public good concept, while well-established, ought really be the exclusive focus of the economic and legal understanding of information.”

COLLABORATION

To collaborate on our research programs, please contact us at:

info@digitalisresearch.com

COMMUNICATION

To receive periodic updates on our work, please sign up below:

THANK YOU.
Oops! Something went wrong while submitting the form.